[1] 2
Lipset and Rokkan: parties form around cleavages, and conflicts are “frozen” based on when democratization occurs
“Party Families” emerge around cleavages, and act as vehicles for their interests (i.e. socialist parties address class cleavage, agrarian parties represent rural interests etc.)
But what do they do with new issues that don’t have a basis in a deep cleavage? (such as EU integration)
Are parties really “frozen”?
Based on semi-annual surveys of area experts
Initially covered European Politics, now covers multiple regions (albeit in separate data sets)
Primary goal: measure party positioning (initially on the EU, but subsequently across a broad range of issues)
Secondary goal: evaluating expert consensus as a measurement
Examples of other quantitative methods for measuring party positions include:
Scaling roll-call votes (NOMINATE)
Analysis of manifestos (Comparative Manifestos Project)
Voter surveys of party positioning (European Election Survey) and elite self-placement (EUandI)
Party-Year level data (one row per party per wave) with the average position, salience, amount of dissent and “blur”
Expert-Party-Year data (one row per expert-party-wave) with the same metrics
Experts contribute a significant but substantively small amount of variation to party placement
(note: this isn’t really related to the CHES per se, but it’s relevant for studying political parties in general)
Laakso and Taagapera (1979): weight parties by their vote share (electoral parties or ENEP) or seat share (parliamentary parties or ENEP)
\[ \text{ENP} = \frac{1}{\sum_{i=1}^{n}p_i^2} \]
Two major parties and one small one:
The CHES data excludes some small parties, ENPP will be slightly deflated from the “real” answer
For ease of comparison, most data sources (including CHES) only look at the lower house in bicameral systems
We’ll use the latest round of the Chapel Hill Expert Survey
Click here for the in-class assignment